In exercise 21.3, we began to investigate different ways of assigning property rights in the presence of

Question:

In exercise 21.3, we began to investigate different ways of assigning property rights in the presence of externalities.

A. Consider again the case of you playing music that disturbs me.

(a) Begin with the assumptions in exercise 21.3 that led to the graph you drew in part (d) of that exercise. Then suppose that the transaction cost of getting together is k. In your graph, indicate for what range of e such a transaction cost will prohibit the efficient outcome from being reached?

(b) If e is assigned outside that range, what will be the outcome?

(c) Next, suppose income€”or endowment€”effects are important; i.e. tastes are not quasilinear. Did we allow for that in exercise 21.3?

(d) Suppose in particular that such endowment effects matter for you but not for me €” with music a normal good for you. Illustrate in a graph what happens to the amount of music as e increases. What happens to p?

(e) If endowment effects matter similarly for you and me, might it be the case that the agreed upon price is unaffected by e? What about the agreed upon amount of music?

(f) Is the Coase Theorem wrong in cases where endowment effects impact the amount of music that is played as property rights are assigned differently?

(g) True or False: As long as transactions costs are zero, we will reach an efficient outcome€”but that outcome (i.e. the amount of music played) might differ depending on whether income effects are important.

B. Suppose first that our tastes are again those given in part B of exercise 21.3.

(a) If you have not done exercise 21.3, do so now and check whether the level of music played will depend on the assignment of property rights e in the absence of transactions costs.

(b) Next, suppose that €” instead of the tastes in exercise 21.3 €” your tastes can be described by the utility function u(x, y) = xαy(1ˆ’α) (where α lies between 0 and 1). My tastes remain unchanged. How much music will be played? Does your answer depend on e €”and does the equilibrium price pˆ— depend on e? . (21.26)

(c) Next, suppose that my utility function is also Cobb-Douglas, taking the form u(x, y) = (1440ˆ’ x)βy(1ˆ’β). Derive again the amount of music that will be played (assuming zero transactions costs). Does your answer depend on e? Does the equilibrium price depend on e?

(d) Explain your results intuitively.

(e) In section 21B.3.4, we went through a numerical exercise to illustrate how the establishment of property rights in the presence of externalities will resolve the €œmarket failure€ in a simple exchange economy. Review the example in the text prior to proceeding. Note that in the text we assigned the property rights in the new market to person 2€”the victim of the externality. But we could have assigned property rights in many other ways (as suggested in our music example). Define x3 once again as the impression of person 1€™s consumption of x1 on person 2; i.e. x3 = x211. We can establish a market for the good x3 by endowing individual 1 with e3 units of x3. This means that individual 1 can produce up to e3 units of x3 €” which is the same as saying that individual 1 can consume up to e3 units of x1 €” without having to pay the market price p3. But if he wants to produce any more x3, he must pay individual 2 p3 for each additional unit above e3. Similarly, under the endowment of e3 for individual 1, individual 2 must pay p3 per unit to individual 1 for any amount of x3 that falls below e3 €” and receives p3 for any amount of x3 above e3. In the numerical example of the text, what did we implicitly set e3 to?

(f) Write down individual 1€™s budget constraint when he is assigned e3 in property rights. (Hint: If x1 < e1, individual 1 will earn p3(e3 ˆ’ x1) but if x1 > e1, he will have to pay p3(x1 ˆ’e3) which is equivalent to saying he will earn p3(e3 ˆ’x1).)

(g) Next, write down individual 2€™s budget constraint.

(h) If you substitute your answer to (e) into the budget constraints in (f ) and (g), you should end up with the budget constraints we used in the numerical example of the text. Do you?

(i) Now suppose that

(1-5) (1-a) and u = (1440– x3)P x,

Suppose further that p1 = 0,

p2 = 1 and p3 = p, and that

In exercise 21.3, we began to investigate different ways of

Can you now interpret the general equilibrium model as modeling our case of you (person 1) bothering me (person 2) with music?

(j) Solve for p and x3 (which is equal to x11). Do you get the same answer as you got when you assumed Cobb-Douglas tastes for both of us in part (c)?

Fantastic news! We've Found the answer you've been seeking!

Step by Step Answer:

Question Posted: