Consider the Barberis et al. [150] model described by equations (9.5)(9.9). In this exercise, following the Appendix

Question:

Consider the Barberis et al. [150] model described by equations (9.5)(9.9). In this exercise, following the Appendix of Barberis et al. [150], we provide the proof of Proposition 9.5. Denote by \((w, c):=\left(\left(w_{t}, c_{t}\right)\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) a self-financing trading-consumption strategy, where the investment strategy \(w_{t+1}\) is parameterized in terms of the amount of wealth invested in the single risky asset between date \(t\) and date \(t+1\). In the context of the present exercise, we assume that a tradingconsumption strategy \((w, c)\) is admissible if \(w_{t}\) is bounded, for all \(t \in \mathbb{N}\). Similarly as in relations (6.4) and (6.19), it is easy to see that a trading-consumption strategy \((\theta, c)\) satisfies the following self-financing condition:

\[W_{t+1}=\left(W_{t}-c_{t}\right) r_{f}+w_{t+1}\left(r_{t+1}-r_{f}\right)+y_{t+1}, \quad \text { for all } t \in \mathbb{N},\]

where \(\left(W_{t}\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) denotes the self-financing wealth process associated with the strategy \((w, c)\) and \(\left(y_{t}\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) is the exogenous income stream.

(i) Let \(\left(w^{*}, c^{*}\right)=\left(\left(w_{t}^{*}, c_{t}^{*}\right)\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) be a trading-consumption strategy satisfying the above self-financing condition. Let \((w, c)=\left(\left(w_{t}, c_{t}\right)\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) be an alternative selffinancing strategy and define the strategy

\[\left(w^{*}+\alpha w, c^{*}+\alpha c\right)=\left(\left(w_{t}^{*}+\alpha w_{t}, c_{t}^{*}+\alpha c_{t}\right)\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}},\]

for \(\alpha \in \mathbb{R}_{+}\). Show that, according to the preference functional (9.7), the difference in the expected utilities associated to

image text in transcribedand \(\left(c^{*}, w^{*}\right)\)


satisfies

 image text in transcribed


where the function \(\hat{v}\) is defined as in the statement of Proposition 9.5.
(ii) Suppose that, for all \(t \in \mathbb{N}\), it holds that \[\begin{gather*}
u^{\prime}\left(c_{t}^{*}\right)=r_{f} \delta \mathbb{E}\left[u^{\prime}\left(c_{t+1}^{*}\right) \mid \mathscr{F}_{t}\right] \tag{9.81}\\u^{\prime}\left(c_{t}^{*}\right)=\delta \mathbb{E}\left[u^{\prime}\left(c_{t+1}^{*}\right) r_{t+1} \mid \mathscr{F}_{t}\right]+\delta b_{t} \mathbb{E}\left[\hat{v}\left(r_{t+1}, z_{t}\right) \mid \mathscr{F}_{t}\right]\tag{9.82}\end{gather*}\]
with \(u(x)=x^{1-\gamma} /(1-\gamma)\) and where the function \(\hat{v}(\cdot)\) is defined as in Proposition 9.5 and the process \(\left(b_{t}\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) is specified by \(b_{t}=b_{0} \bar{c}_{t}^{-\gamma}\), for all \(t \in \mathbb{N}\). Show that, for all \(t \in \mathbb{N}\), it holds that \(\mathbb{E}\left[u^{\prime}\left(c_{t}^{*}\right) \alpha c_{t}+\alpha w_{t+1} \delta b_{t} \hat{v}\left(r_{t+1}, z_{t}\right) \mid \mathscr{F}_{t}\right]=u^{\prime}\left(c_{t}^{*}\right) \alpha W_{t}-\delta \mathbb{E}\left[u^{\prime}\left(c_{t+1}^{*}\right) \alpha W_{t+1} \mid \mathscr{F}_{t}\right]\), where \(\left(W_{t}\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) is the wealth process associated to the self-financing strategy \((w, c)\).
(iii) Deduce that

 image text in transcribed

As explained in Barberis et al. [150, Appendix], the right-hand side of the last equality vanishes if \(W_{0}=0\) and the following condition holds:
\[\log \delta-\gamma g_{c}+g_{d}+\frac{\gamma^{2} \sigma_{c}^{2}-2 \gamma ho \sigma_{c} \sigma_{d}+\sigma_{d}^{2}}{2}

This shows that the Euler conditions (9.81)-(9.82) are necessary and sufficient for the optimality of the strategy \(\left(\left(\theta_{t}^{*}, c_{t}^{*}\right)\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\).
(iv) Show that the risk free return \(r_{f}\) given in (9.10) satisfies the Euler condition (9.81) when the consumption process \(\left(c_{t}^{*}\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\) is given by the aggregate per capita consumption process \(\left(\bar{c}_{t}\right)_{t \in \mathbb{N}}\).


(v) Suppose that the equilibrium price-dividend ratio of the risky asset satisfies \[\frac{p_{t}^{*}}{d_{t}}=f\left(z_{t}\right), \quad \text { for all } t \in \mathbb{N}\]
for a suitable function \(f(\cdot)\). Show that

 image text in transcribed

Deduce that condition (9.11) of Proposition 9.5 implies that the Euler optimality condition (9.82) holds.
(vi) Deduce that the strategy of consuming \(c_{t}^{*}=\bar{c}_{t}=d_{t}+y_{t}\), for all \(t \in \mathbb{N}\), and holding the market supply of the risky asset satisfies the Euler conditions (9.81)-(9.82) and the claim of Proposition 9.5 follows.

Fantastic news! We've Found the answer you've been seeking!

Step by Step Answer:

Related Book For  answer-question
Question Posted: